Tax
administration, heal thyself
Tax rate increases are in the air, especially since all of us have
read about the fiscal cliff in the US, the 99 per cent vs 1 per cent fashion,
President Hollande of France (an economy closest to us in its non-economic and
Luddite views) proposing prohibitive tax rates on the rich, etc.
C. Rangarajan, advisor to
the prime minister, stated, appropriately on Financial Inclusion day, that
"one need not disturb the structure of income tax system as it is now. But
add a surcharge for income above [a] particular level. I believe as we go
along, we need to raise more revenues and the people with larger incomes must
be willing to contribute more".
Note the populist appeal to
the super-rich. They should be willing — or else, off with their heads
(income). As discussed in my earlier article, Taxing the rich and other
fantasies (IE, January 23), there is precious little evidence to support
Rangarajan's recommendation. What the data do suggest, as documented
extensively below, is that the reason tax revenue is considerably below
potential is because the middle income group, those earning between Rs 5 to Rs 10
lakh, is quite "unwilling" to pay taxes, even at an average tax rate
of 10 per cent! And that the most "willing" are the super-rich, those
earning above Rs 20 lakh a year. The raise tax rates recommendation should be
junked, especially since stable tax rates have generated "good" tax
revenue and allowed compliance to increase more than threefold from the
abysmally low levels which prevailed prior to the 1997-98 budget.
Until 2005-06, India, via
CAG reports on the ministry of finance, had access to data, some data, on the
distribution of income and taxation. After that — whoosh — all the information
stopped. Now the reports only reveal the total number of taxpayers in the
economy, about 3.24 crore, out of which about 1 crore file tax returns but
don't pay any tax because their incomes are below Rs 1.8 lakh.
What the tax department,
and all of us, should be interested in is maximising tax revenue. The table
reports all the relevant tax parameters for fiscal 2011-12 — who pays taxes,
who should pay taxes, rates of taxation, revenue collected, etc.
Some suggestive
conclusions:
The total amount of
personal income tax (PIT) that could have been collected in 2011-12 was Rs
517,000 crore or Rs 5.17 trillion. The total amount that was collected was Rs
1.72 trillion indicating an overall compliance rate of 33 per cent. So
two-thirds of the taxable population avoided paying taxes altogether or paid
two-thirds less taxes than they should have.
The dominantly large share
of the flow of black money each year is indicated by the gap in tax collected
and tax due and for 2011-12 this gap, Rs 3.45 trillion, is about 4 per cent of
GDP. For the 10 years 2002-03 to 2011-12, 4 per cent of average GDP is Rs 20
trillion. This suggests that the recent estimates pegging black money at around
Rs 25 trillion are in the right ballpark — and that our "missing tax"
estimates are broadly correct.
The largest share of
missing taxes is among those earning between Rs 5 to Rs 10 lakh a year. They
are in the top 7 per cent of the population, they number around 25 million, and
only about 10 per cent of such individuals pay any tax. How much missing taxes
is in this group, a group for which the average tax rate is only 10 per cent?
About equal to the entire tax collected in 2011-12: Rs 150 thousand crore.
About Rs 1 trillion is lost
among those earning between Rs 10 and Rs 20 lakh a year. Such individuals are
in the top 2 per cent of the population, and only a third of such individuals
pay any tax.
The super-rich or those
earning more than Rs 20 lakh a year: there were 88 lakh such individuals and 58
lakh paid taxes, yielding a compliance rate of 66 per cent. Missing taxes for
this group: Rs 0.46 trillion, or only 13 per cent of the entire amount of PIT
missing in India.
If compliance levels stay
the same, a surcharge of 3 per cent on super-rich incomes will yield about Rs
2,600 crore. Alternatively, the government could make an effort, with support
from its tax administration officials, to reduce corruption, reduce black money,
and increase taxation of the top 7 per cent. If compliance in this group was
brought to only the average of the economy — that is, 30 per cent — that alone
would generate an extra Rs 35,000 crore, that is, five million extra taxpayers,
paying an average tax rate of only 10 per cent, on average incomes of Rs 7
lakh. Okay, if tax administration increased compliance by only 3 percentage
points, from 10 per cent to 13 per cent among this middle income group of Rs 5
to Rs 10 lakh, the extra revenue gained would be Rs 5,250 crore or double that
gained from putting a 3 per cent surcharge on the super-rich.
These simple calculations
yield at least three recommendations. First, it should be mandatory for the
finance ministry to release data on tax compliance by income groups — a
practice common in most economies in the world. Surely, no one can oppose the
release of this statistic, so why isn't it being practised? Possibly because it
will cast a very black shadow on the workings of the tax administration in India?
Second, the biggest revenue gainer is via an increase in compliance, especially
for the middle income group. Third, stop thinking of populist measures like
surcharges on the super rich, or copy French measures like increasing tax rates
for anybody. If any such measures are introduced in the budget, it would not be
a "responsible" budget as the finance minister has promised — and not
responsible by a long shot.
19-08-2013
The
needless battle
Rupee defence strategy has deepened the gathering
gloom on the India growth story.
The defence of the rupee is going horribly
wrong. It has damaged two sources of hope for a growth pick-up in India —
monetary policy easing and India's commitment to economic reform. When Chairman
Ben Bernanke of the Fed talked about tapering quantitative easing in the US, it
was expected that there would be pressure on emerging market currencies.
Countries with weaker economies, and with larger current account deficits were
likely to see more currency volatility. Instead of talking about this source of
pressure, which all emerging markets faced when the dollar started
appreciating, the government decided to step in to defend the rupee.
Evidence from across the world shows that a
currency defence often fails. Every government trying to stabilise a currency
is, therefore, fully aware of the chances of failure. A careful cost-benefit
analysis of its strategy is thus an important pre-condition to initiating a
defence. Since the global currency turmoil started, the government has been
rolling out measures such as currency market controls, import duties on gold
and silver, bans on purchase of gold coins and tightening of capital controls
to stabilise the rupee. These dirigiste solutions seem oblivious of their
likely impact on market expectations. They are based on central planning
notions of bans and restrictions being the solutions to the economy's problems.
First came restrictions on currency derivatives
markets by Sebi and the RBI. These markets inform people of expectations about
the currency. This information may be unpleasant. The government may disagree
with it. But instead of listening to what the market was saying, the
authorities chose to try to silence it. Restrictions reduced the extent to
which people could hedge their currency risk. This was a bad move, especially
since the rupee was expected to become more volatile. It made investors less
willing to buy rupee assets. Trading volumes on domestic currency derivatives
markets fell sharply and the cost of hedging increased. Instead of making rupee
assets more attractive, these measures have made them less attractive. Further,
the restrictions have undermined the market's confidence about the government's
commitment to financial market liberalisation.
Next came the liquidity squeeze and an increase
in short-term interest rates. The complicated strategy hoped to keep long-term
interest rates low. This, too, failed. When the rate hike saw a transmission of
higher rates to treasury bill rates, long-term bond yields and deposit rates,
it became increasingly clear that sooner or later bank lending rates would go
up. To prevent that, the RBI kept the repo and CRR rate unchanged. This left
the market in complete confusion. Were interest rates going to rise or fall?
Statements by the authorities that the tightening was temporary till the rupee
stabilises provided little comfort. Could the currency stabilise before US
monetary policy went back to normal? How long was "temporary"? In an
environment in which a monetary easing was expected to help push up growth,
this sudden tightening was a shock. Interest rates are still high. The measures
have undermined confidence about monetary policy easing.
After the liquidity squeeze failed to restore
rupee stability, came tariff hikes and restrictions on gold and silver imports
and tightening of capital controls under FEMA. Restrictions have been imposed
on capital outflows by firms and households. Already, firms were suffering from
the difficulties of the policy environment. If some of them were going to stay
healthy by investing abroad, that was made more cumbersome. Hardly any money
was going out by individuals investing abroad. But putting a restriction on
these trickles sent out a bad signal to an already nervous market. These
measures did not inspire confidence that the government's focus was investment
and growth. Worse, they suggested that India's economic reforms are not
deep-seated and can be reversed for short-term ends.
With the opening up of trade and the capital
account, the currency market has grown very large. Old solutions, like selling
a few billion dollars from our reserves to prevent appreciation, no longer
work. Out of the three corners of the impossible trinity, a country can choose
only two. For the last two decades, India had chosen to move towards an open
economy and a flexible exchange rate. In the face of the QE tapering, it means
choosing between rupee stability and lowering interest rates. But the
government did not like having to make the choice. It wanted both. The only way
to control the currency in such a situation is to close the economy. When the
size of the market has shrunk adequately, the RBI can intervene and prevent
depreciation without much loss of reserves.
If the rupee remains volatile, the government
has to choose to either roll out the next measure it has on its list, or to
find an exit route. FEMA allows the RBI and government to shut off all
cross-border transactions for sale and purchase of assets. The market believes
that as long at the rupee defence strategy remains in place, the authorities
might impose restrictions on various other capital flows. This expectation has
caused further gloom.
We should not lose sight of the big picture of
Indian economic policy. The story of the last 20 years is one of slow but
steady economic reform resulting in 7 per cent trend GDP growth. The day we
walk away from the promise of slow but steady reform, the expectation of future
productivity growth is shattered. This adversely affects the credit rating of
India, stock prices, investment in India by locals and by foreigners, and
capital flight from India. The needless battle the government has picked on the
rupee, and the measures it has taken, have reinforced the already growing
despondence about economic reforms. It has raised new questions on the India
growth story. The government must immediately undo all the steps that have
reversed economic reforms of trade or finance or capital account
liberalisation. Otherwise, we will suffer deeper damage to the prospect of high
GDP growth
No comments:
Post a Comment